Describes the way in which a variable such as a stock price, exchange rate or interest rate changes through time
Incorporates uncertainties
Example of Stochastic Processes
Each day a stock price: increases by $1 with probability 30, stays the same with probability 50%, reduces by $1 with probability 20%
Each day a stock price change is drawn from a normal distribution with mean $0.2 and standard deviation $1
Markov Processes
In a Markov process future movements in a variable depend only on where we are, not the history of how we got to where we are
Is the process followed by the temperature at a certain place Markov?
We assume that stock prices follow Markov processes
Weak-Form Market Efficiency
This asserts that it is impossible to produce consistently superior returns with a trading rule based on the past history of stock prices. In other words technical analysis does not work.
A Markov process for stock prices is consistent with weak-form market efficiency
Variances & Standard Deviations
In Markov processes changes in successive periods of time are independent
This means that variances are additive
Standard deviations are not additive
In our example it is correct to say that the variance is 100 per year.
It is strictly speaking not correct to say that the standard deviation is 10 per year.
A Wiener Process
Define f(μ,ν) as a normal distribution with mean μ and variance ν
A variable z follows a Wiener process if
The change in z in a small interval of time Δt is Δz
Δz=ϵΔt where ϵ∼f(0,1)
The values of Δz for any 2 different (non-overlapping) periods of time are independent
If we know the stochastic process followed by x, Itoˆ's lemma tells us the stochastic process followed by some function G(x,t). When dx=a(x,t)dt+b(x,t)dz then dG=(∂x∂Ga+∂t∂G+21∂x2∂2Gb2)dt+∂x∂Gbdz
Since a derivative is a function of the price of the underlying asset and time, Itoˆ's lemma plays an important part in the analysis of derivatives
Applications of Itoˆ's Lemma to A Stock Price Process
Suppose the stock price process is dS=μSdt+σSdz
For a function G of S and t we have dG=(∂S∂GμS+∂t∂G+21∂S2∂2Gσ2S2)dt+∂S∂GσSdz
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
The Stock Price Assumption
The Stock Price Assumption
Consider a stock whose price is S
In a short period of time of length Δt, the return on the stock is normally distributed: SΔS≈ϕ(μΔt,σ2Δt)
So the price ST is lognormal distributed lnST−lnS0≈ϕ[(μ−2σ2)T,σ2T]
or lnST≈ϕ[lnS0+(μ−2σ2)T,σ2T]
Continuously Compounded Return
If x is the realized continuously compounded return we have ST=S0exT x=T1lnS0ST x≈(μ−2σ2,Tσ2)
The Expected Return
The expected value of the stock price is S0eμT
The expected return on the stock is μ−2σ2 not μ
The reason is that, ln[E(ST/S0)] and E[ln(ST/S0)] are not the same
μ vs. μ−2σ2
μ is the expected return in a very short time, Δt, expressed with a compounding frequency of Δt
μ−2σ2 is the expected return in a long period of time expressed with continuous compounding (or, to a good approximation, with a compounding frequency of Δt)
Volatility
The Volatility
The volatility is the standard deviation of the continuously compounded rate of return in 1 year
The standard deviation of the return in a short time period time Δt is approximately σΔt
If a stock price is $50 and its volatility is 25% per year what is the standard deviation of the price change in one day?
Estimating Volatility
Take observations S0,S1,…,Sn at intervals of t years (e.g. for weekly data t=1/52)
Calculate the continuously compounded return in each interval as: ui=ln(Si−1Si)
Calculate the standard deviation, s , of the ui's
The historical volatility estimate is: σ^=τs
Nature of Volatility
Volatility is usually much greater when the market is open (i.e. the asset is trading) than when it is closed
For this reason time is usually measured in ``trading days'' not calendar days when options are valued
It is assumed that there are 252 trading days in one year for most assets
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Black-Scholes-Merton: The Big Idea
The option price and the stock price depend on the same underlying source of uncertainty
We can form a portfolio consisting of the stock and the option which eliminates this source of uncertainty
The portfolio is instantaneously riskless and must instantaneously earn the risk-free rate
This leads to the Black-Scholes-Merton differential equation
The Derivation of the Black-Scholes-Merton Differential Equation
The value of the portfolio Π=−f+∂S∂fS ΔΠ=−Δf+∂S∂fΔS
Since the portfolio is risk-free, we have ΔΠ=rΠΔt −Δf+∂S∂fΔS=r(−f+∂S∂fS)Δt
So, the Black-Scholes-Merton Differential Equation is ∂t∂f+rS∂S∂f+21σ2S2∂S2∂2f=rf
Any security whose price is dependent on the stock price satisfies the differential equation
The particular security being valued is determined by the boundary conditions of the differential equation
In a forward contract the boundary condition is f=S−K when t=T
The solution to the equation is f=S−Ke−r(T−t)
Black-Scholes-Merton Pricing for Options
c=S0N(d1)−Ke−rTN(d2) p=Ke−rTN(−d2)−S0N(d1)
where d1=σTln(S0/K)+(r+σ2/2)T d2=σTln(S0/K)+(r−σ2/2)T=d1−σT
Properties of Black-Scholes Formula
As S0 becomes very large c tends to S0−Ke−rT and p tends to zero
As S0 becomes very small c tends to zero and p tends to Ke−rT−S0
What happens as σ becomes very large?
What happens as T becomes very large?
Understanding Black-Scholes
The formula c=e−rTN(d2)(S0erTN(d1)/N(d2)−K)
e−rT: Discount rate
N(d2): Probability of exercise
erTN(d1)/N(d2): Expected percentage increase in stock price if option is exercised
K: Strike price paid if option is exercised
Risk-Neutral Valuation
Risk-Neutral Valuation
Risk-Neutral Valuation
The variable μ does not appear in the Black-Scholes-Merton differential equation
The equation is independent of all variables affected by risk preference
The solution to the differential equation is therefore the same in a risk-free world as it is in the real world
This leads to the principle of risk-neutral valuation
Applying Risk-Neutral Valuation
[1] Assume that the expected return from the stock price is the risk-free rate
[2] Calculate the expected payoff from the option
[3] Discount at the risk-free rate
Option Sensitivities: Greeks
Greeks
The Taylor Expansion df=∂S∂fdS+21∂S2∂2fdS2+∂r∂fdr+∂r∗∂fdr∗+∂σ∂fdσ+∂τ∂fdτ+…